The finance ministers of the G20 endorsed the agreement reached by 130 countries on fundamental changes to how the profits of the largest multinationals should be taxed. It includes the eye-catching proposal for a global minimum corporate tax rate of at least 15%.
Similar to the earlier communiqué from G7 finance ministers endorsing
the proposals in principle, this represented another important step towards a
radical overhaul of the international tax system. Following a period of
understandable scepticism that – given the scale of agreement required – this
project could get off the ground, it now looks a realistic possibility that the
proposals may actually come into force.
Businesses should start thinking seriously about
how these proposals may affect them.
Notwithstanding the current triumphant mood amongst
those sponsoring these proposals, there remain technical and political
obstacles that could yet derail the whole endeavour. This includes the domestic
legislative changes required to pass through each signatory jurisdiction – with
a critical mass needed to ensure the project is a success.
This note sets out what you need to know about what
the proposals might mean in practice and what is likely to happen next.
What problem is the OECD/G20/G7
trying to solve?
Under the current international tax system, tax is
generally paid in the jurisdictions where a company has a physical presence. An
increasingly digitized world has meant that revenue can be generated in places
where – under current rules – a business has no taxable presence. Globalisation
and the attendant rise of multinational groups has meant there are more
opportunities to generate profits outside of the jurisdictions in which
companies’ customers are located.
The genesis of the OECD project was therefore a
desire to modernise the tax system to ensure value derived by businesses
through digitalisation is properly taxed where it is created and limit the
reduction in effective tax rate that businesses can achieve through their group
arrangements. While the original “BEPS” project made progress towards these
ends, many of the difficult questions around a digitalised economy were left
unanswered.
In parallel, some jurisdictions have spoken of the
need to avoid a “race to the bottom” – in the absence of a new global
settlement, countries face an incentive to keep reducing their tax rates to
attract investment from international (often, digital) businesses which would
otherwise chose to locate themselves in jurisdictions offering a lower tax
environment.
What are the proposals that have
now been agreed?
For two broad problems there are two broad sets of
solutions – or “Pillars”, to use the OECD nomenclature.
- “Pillar
One” allocates new taxing rights to market jurisdictions, including where
a multinational lacks physical presence in their territory. Following the
Biden administration’s intervention earlier this year, the focus is no
longer on “tech” companies (which the US perceived as unfair) but is aimed
instead at the “largest” companies (determined by global revenue and
profitability).
- In-scope
companies will be those with turnover exceeding EUR 20bn (although this
will fall to EUR 10bn after seven years if implementation is successful)
who will have to allocate 20—30% of their profits in excess of a 10%
margin to the countries where they operate (known as “Amount A”). Their
market jurisdictions will be determined using an allocation key, which
under current proposals would mean countries where the group derives at
least €1mn in revenue (or €250,000 for countries with GDP below €40bn).
- “Pillar
Two” will set a global minimum corporation tax rate of at least 15%. This
is not an obligation for jurisdictions to change their nominal rates, but
rather would mean that signatory countries agree to ensure multinationals
headquartered in their jurisdictions have paid this rate of tax across
their foreign controlled subsidiaries (the “Income Inclusion Rule”).
- In
practice this would involve comparing the effective tax rate of profits
from each subsidiary jurisdiction to the agreed minimum tax rate, and
topping up any shortfall as required on a country by country basis (with
such tax paid in the headquarter jurisdiction, where they have signed up).
This would remove any tax advantage to establishing subsidiaries in low
tax jurisdictions.
- Where
a parent company is not located in a signatory jurisdiction, the
“Undertaxed Payment Rule” is designed to support the same end goal by allowing
participating countries to disallow deductions for base eroding payments
made to low tax countries.
- The
final rule is the “Subject to Tax” rule which is designed to ensure source
jurisdictions that have ceded taxing rights under a treaty can apply a
top-up tax to the agreed minimum rate (between 7.5% - 9% on gross income,
rather than 15% on net profits) on certain related party payments.
The US quid pro quo: goodbye to
digital services taxes (DSTs)
In return for agreeing to proposals that would see
a shift in taxing rights over its tech companies away from the US, other deal
signatories have committed to the abolition of domestic DSTs (which primarily
targeted American tech companies). This represents the second limb of the US
success in pivoting the tax spotlight away from its tech giants (the first one
being the reframing of the scope of Pillar One in terms of size rather than
provision of digital services).
The technical detail has
advanced, but many key questions remain
The OECD’s most recent statement (on 1 July 2021)
was welcome in confirming the consensus that had been reached on several
outstanding points, such as whether financial services will be excluded from
the scope of Pillar One (they will, as will the extractives sector) and whether
there will be any exclusions from the minimum tax rate (there will be a
“substance” carve-out based on tangible assets and payroll in a jurisdiction,
and a de minimis exclusion for certain jurisdictions below a set
threshold).
But many questions remain unanswered and core
details have yet to be worked out:
Pillar One
- Revenue
sourcing – the end market-jurisdiction where goods or services are used or
consumed is the indicator for identifying revenue in a market jurisdiction
but the question of whether revenue is derived from a market is not always
straightforward (consider a free-to-use social media platform or a
manufacturer with an extended supply-chain). The OECD statement confirms
that “detailed source rules for specific categories of transactions” will
need to be developed – but doesn’t give away much about what these will
look like.
- Segmentation
– this is the approach of applying the Pillar One rules to particular
business lines of a multinational rather than its profits in aggregate,
which enables the rules to apply to sufficiently profitable streams where
these would otherwise be excluded because the multinational isn’t in
aggregate sufficiently profitable.
- The
“Amount B” proposal – the intention of Amount B is to simplify transfer
pricing rules by introducing standardised remuneration of related party
distributors that perform certain marketing and distribution activities,
however the details of this aspect have been delayed.
Pillar Two
- Scope
– the minimum tax proposal will principally apply to large groups with
turnover in excess of EUR 750m, however countries will have the ability to
apply a lower threshold to groups headquartered in their country if they
wish. The threshold for the subject to tax rule has not been confirmed in
the agreement therefore this could have widespread implications for
smaller groups.
- Tax
base - an agreed global standard tax base will need to be devised to
determine the ETR that triggers the “GloBE rules” (the collective name for
all three of the Income Inclusion, Undertaxed Payment and Subject to Tax
Rules). The challenge is agreeing which tax adjustments are acceptable,
for the purposes of ascertaining how much tax needs to be topped up. There
are a wide range of possible adjustments, each with their own particular
rationale (capital allowances, participation exemptions and loss relief to
name a few), and political agreement will need to be reached.
- Substance-based
carve-out – this seeks to carve out income that provides at least 5%
return on tangible assets and payroll (at least 7.5% in the five year
transition period). Discussions, or negotiations are likely to continue on
this important exclusion as it will have a pivotal role in the value of
certain incentive regimes like the patent box.
- Interaction
with the US foreign profits regime known as GILTI – the way in which the
US GILTI regime will co-exist with the global minimum tax rules is still
under discussion. In particular, Pillar Two operates on a
jurisdiction-by-jurisdiction basis but GILTI takes a blended approach and
furthermore, the GILTI rate is currently below the proposed minimum of
15%.
Will this actually happen?
Although substantial progress has been made,
significant hurdles remain to be cleared between now and a world in which
Pillar One and Pillar Two are fully functional.
- Various
jurisdictions remain reticent: several countries out of the OECD’s
139-strong Inclusive Framework have not yet signed up to the deal, most
notably Ireland which has used domestic tax policy to support its policy
of attracting foreign investment.
- Domestic
politics (generally): it is one thing a country agreeing in principle to
adopt these measures, but that is really just the beginning. Implementing
these proposals will require updates to both domestic legislation and
bilateral treaties, the success of which will depend on the political
situation in each country.
- Domestic
politics (the US): despite the Biden administration’s enthusiasm for the
deal, uncertainty over whether the proposals will make their way through
the US legislature presents one of the greatest threats to the proposals’
success. The Biden administration is pursuing domestic tax reform at the
same time as this international project, and it is not clear that the one
can survive without the other. The measures do not enjoy bi-partisan
support, and the Senate currently divides 50:50 on party lines (with the
Vice President holding a casting vote).
No comments:
Post a Comment